Federal Reserve chairman Ben Bernanke used last week as an
opportunity to address the Fed's exit strategy of removing the bank
reserves that have been pumped into the banking system since
September of last year. Of course, this will not happen until the
Fed and our political leaders feel that both the banking system and
the economy is on considerably sounder footing and tighter monetary
policy is less likely to toss the economy back into the ditch. I
say political leaders because the Fed has lost a considerable
amount of its "independence" and pressure will be a tool wielded by
our politicians (especially as elections near). Given the events of
this week, it is a good opportunity to review the state of the Fed
balance sheet, some if its recent operations, and a few key items
in Bernanke's plan to drain reserves from the banking system at the
"appropriate time". I will begin with a little background info that
you can also find in previous articles, but presented a bit
differently here.
Total reserves in the banking system now stand at $805 billion
(seasonally adjusted as of 7/15), with $743 billion being excess
reserves held by the banking system on deposit with the Federal
Reserve. Remember that reserves are created when the Fed purchases
assets. Each member bank has a reserve account with the Fed. When
the Fed purchases assets, the aggregate reserves in these accounts
rise (reserves are added to the banking system). When the Fed sells
assets, the aggregate reserves in these accounts fall (reserves are
drained from the banking system). This modification on the
liability side of the Fed balance sheet is offset by an equal
operation on the asset side of the Fed balance sheet.
Ex. 1
Fed action:
Fed purchases $100 billion of Treasuries
Result:
Asset side of the Fed balance sheet increases by $100 billion in
the Treasuries category. Bank reserves on the liability side of the
Fed balance sheet increases by $100 billion.
Ex. 2
Fed action:
Fed sells $100 billion of Treasuries
Result:
Asset side of the Fed balance sheet decreases by $100 billion in
the Treasuries category. Bank reserves on the liability side of the
Fed balance sheet decreases by $100 billion.
Thus, you can see how the Fed expands and contracts its balance
sheet. The Fed has conducted a myriad of lending and purchase
programs since the onset of the financial crisis. However, until
September of last year, the Fed was sterilizing these injections by
selling treasuries from its portfolio. These Fed asset sales drain
reserves from the banking system, which in this case offset the
other purchases that were made. So, the net effect was that the Fed
was mostly swapping good debt (treasuries) for questionable debt
(various securities held by the banks that were not receiving bids
in the free market) ... with the amount of unsterilized injections
exactly enough to achieve the falling federal funds rate target.
The Fed ceased its reserve neutral policy last September and
flooded the system with reserves over the next four months. Reserve
levels have been mostly maintained since the end of last year
(ranging between $700 billion and $932 billion with normal being
between $10 and $20 billion).
Managing a balance sheet of this size and diversity is much more
involved. Reserves have been fluctuating due to the cessation of
certain programs (drains reserves), the introduction of new ones
(injects or drains reserves depending on the program), increases or
decreases in the amounts of assets purchased or currency swaps with
foreign central banks (injects or drains reserves), and the
maturing of Fed assets (drains reserves). Additionally, the average
maturity of assets held by the Fed continues to rise, making an
ultimate exit strategy even more interesting (interest rate risk).
The principal measures introduced this year by the Fed include the
outright purchase of longer dated treasuries, the purchase of
mortgage-backed securities (MBSs) backed by Fannie Mae and Freddie
Mac (Agency MBSs), and Agency debt itself. Thus far the Fed has
purchased more than $213 billion of the $300 billion it may
purchase under the current treasury purchase program. The Fed has
purchased $545 billion in MBSs ($1.25 trillion max) and $102
billion in Agency debt ($200 billion max). The following link
provides a nice graphical view of the asset side of the Fed balance
sheet ... [See WSJ Blogs: Real time Economics] The Federal
Reserve Bank of Cleveland also provides a nice detailed overview in
graphical form [See Credit Easing Policy Tools]
What is so alarming about the level of excess reserves in the
banking system? As stated many times in prior articles, quite
simply the potential for serious inflation and a future boom/bust
cycle worse than the one we are currently experiencing. The
monetary base (outstanding currency in circulation + bank reserves)
sits at about $1.673 trillion. This is approximately where it was
at the end of last year, but double that of a year ago. However,
narrow money supply growth remains tepid this year. The amount of
lending in the system is mostly being offset by debt repayment
(which is deflationary). As of the end of June, M1 has grown only
1.92% since the end of last year. M1 actually had negative growth
from the end of last year through May. M2 growth since the end of
last year has been tepid as well (2.31%). But the money supply will
increase once the banks feel it is safe to ... 1) Lend these vastly
increased reserves and/or 2) Invest these reserves in other
securities (Ex. treasuries) ... and are less encouraged by the Fed
to keep their reserves on deposit (via the payment of interest on
required and excess reserves held by depository institutions). The
key here is to watch the banks. They know the quality of their
balance sheets and will engage once they are comfortable with their
own capitalization levels, feel that the economy is turning, and
the yield spreads are there. For the time being, they are
comfortable with the slow recapitalization of the banking system
being conducted by the Fed (it is all about buying time), at the
ultimate expense of the taxpayer. Of course, a timely Fed exit is
supposed to mitigate this potential future inflationary problem.
Given the track record of the Fed (and more importantly, the
difficulty of such timing), I am not optimistic in this
regard.
Now that we have discussed the size of the Fed balance sheet, we
should address quality. It is important to note that the asset side
of the Fed balance sheet is what underpins the outstanding currency
in our system, the bank reserves, and ultimately our money supply.
Thus, the quality of these assets (and as you will see later, the
current value of these assets) is of real importance. It would be
an understatement to say that the quality of assets held by the Fed
has declined since the onset of the financial crisis. What was once
principally treasuries backing our money is now of considerably
lesser quality. These currently held assets include Agency MBSs,
Agency debt, various loan programs where the Fed takes similar
assets as collateral, foreign currency swaps, and of course
treasuries. The Fed also holds Gold as an asset, but this only
amounts to about $250 billion at current prices (it is represented
at $42.22/oz. on the Fed balance sheet). It will not be long until
the amount of MBSs surpass the amount of treasuries held by the
Fed. So, keep this in mind as we review Bernanke's exit
strategy.
Exit Strategy?
Bernanke wrote an Op-Ed in the Tuesday (7/21) edition of the Wall
Street Journal. The purpose of this editorial was to assuage
investors that the Fed in fact does have a plan to withdraw the
immense amount of reserves injected by the Fed during this crisis.
The editorial can be found here ...
Candidate tools outlined in Bernanke's exit strategy:
- Supplementing interest paid by the Federal Reserve on
bank reserves on deposit with the Federal Reserve
- Execution of large scale reverse-repurchase
agreements
- Issuance of new Treasury debt with the proceeds deposited
at the Federal Reserve
- Offering interest bearing term deposits to
banks
- Asset sales from Federal Reserve holdings
All of these options drain reserves from the banking
system. However, most are more temporary in nature. The only new
option outlined by Bernanke is the Federal Reserve offering term
deposits to banks (#4 above). As discussed, the Fed already pays
interest on required and excess reserves held by depository
institutions, which is essentially the Fed borrowing from the
public. Since a market for lending/borrowing federal funds is
offered daily, the banks can choose to leave their reserves on
deposit with the Fed and earn interest (currently 0.25%) or lend in
the federal funds market (typically paying less than 0.25%).
Offering term deposits would simply lock up these reserves for a
longer period of time, allowing some of the planning variables in
the Fed equations to become more constant. But this option is still
only temporary and it is one that costs the taxpayers (via smaller
Fed payments to the Treasury). Raising the interest rate paid on
reserves (term and non-term) will provide more aid to the banks,
but determining the correct rate of interest that will sterilize
these reserves (without going overboard) will be very difficult and
bias will likely be to the inflationary side (lower rate of
interest). This rate will put somewhat of a floor under the federal
funds rate. The exception to this floor is that there are
non-depository institutions (Ex. Fannie Mae, Freddie Mac, non-bank
primary dealers) that participate in the federal funds market, but
are not eligible to receive interest on reserves. Hence, they may
undercut the rate paid on reserves which results in a nice
arbitrage opportunity for the banks.
Executing large scale reverse-repurchase agreements are certainly
temporary (#2 above). When the Fed closes this transaction, it will
inject reserves (actually, slightly more than originally drained)
back into the system. The Fed is already engaged with the Treasury
in the Treasury Supplemental Financing Program (TSFP) (an
implementation of #3 above). Here, the Treasury auctions debt and
deposits the proceeds with the Fed in a special Treasury account
(represented as a Fed liability). This drains reserves from the
banking system as the Treasury is not a depository institution and
is in effect the Treasury borrowing on behalf of the Fed. However,
the reserves flow back into the system when these auctioned
securities mature. This program reached a peak of about $559
billion last year. But these auctions have ceased and the
maturation of these securities has left a balance of about $200
billion. Operating this facility again will only add to the amount
of debt the Treasury will need to auction in the coming quarters.
You also have the issue of losing even more Fed independence from
the government (Treasury) as it depends on the Treasury to execute
such a program.
But I want to focus more on the last item above (#5) as it is not
being discussed in terms of the quality of assets being held by the
Fed. The assumption has been that the Fed will be able to drain all
(or most) of the reserves it originally created. But since the Fed
is going further out on the yield curve with treasuries, it is more
susceptible to interest rate risk. If the Fed were to drain
reserves by selling these longer term treasury assets (which would
also put upward pressure on interest rates), the price that
these assets would fetch would quite likely not be enough to drain
the amount of reserves originally created when it purchased
them. Also as I have previously discussed, the
composition of the balance sheet is getting shakier. I think that
this may ultimately be the larger problem, as opposed to the sheer
size. This may become a serious problem as MBSs, longer term
treasuries, and other assets held by the Fed decline in value
relative to their inflated purchase price (especially as the Fed
commences the selling of these assets and interest rates rise). In
other words, simply the Fed saying that it will execute a proper
exit strategy (draining the reserves it created) is not
enough with the prices of their assets falling.
Meanwhile, much more debt remains to be auctioned (both
domestically and globally). There will be much competition for
scarce funds globally, which will place upward pressure on interest
rates. Thus, the Fed will likely find itself in a position where
the assets it holds are falling in price while it needs to assist
the Treasury market by purchasing treasury debt ... which will add
reserves to the banking system making a successful execution of the
Fed exit strategy even more difficult. I think that eventually,
another option may surface, but will require congressional
approval. I have discussed it in prior missives ... the issuance of
Federal Reserve interest bearing debt (which would compete with
Treasury debt).
Even if all of the above works nicely in favor of the Federal
Reserve (quite unlikely), there is always the issue of timing. If
the Fed is late in draining these massive reserves (and "late"
probably needs to happen if we are to have an economic rebound ...
albeit false and temporary), the banks will already have expanded
the money supply (maybe considerably) and we will experience an
unhealthy dose of inflation which could lead to serious price
inflation and another asset bubble. Can anyone cite a time when the
Fed timing has been correct? I cannot.